Licensing Strategies in the Presence of Patent Thickets

Lihui Lin (2011) “Licensing Strategies in the Presence of Patent Thickets."Journal of Product Innovation Management, Volume 28, Issue 5, pages 698–725, September 2011. DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-5885.2011.00835.x. link to Wiley;;;

Notes by yinung

本文之理論模型是以 2-stage, backward-induction 的方式來推理,其模型之數學形式,可供參考。

文獻上未討論不同 licensing contracts 對 patent thickets, royalty stacking, double marginalization 之影響。

賽局理論模型; 研究下游廠商向上游尋求 N 個 licenses 授權, 其討論 5 種 licensing contract 如下:

  • Quantity-Based Royalty Licenses

下游每單位 output 授權費 u

  • Downstream firm with no bargaining power
    上游完全決定 u (given 下游只能全盤接受, 在本文中稱之 researvation payoff = 0)
  • Downstream firm with any reservation payoff
    上游只要選一個 u 使下游的 payoffs >= reservation payoffs 即可;故下游 bargaining power 會大,則 u 會愈小
  • Revenue-Based Royalty Licenses (by Goldscheider, 1995)
上游向下游收取 r 比例之收入為授權費
  • Profit-Based Royalty Licenses

the price of the final product is independent of the royalty rate and the distribution of bargaining power.

  • Fixed-Fee Licenses

just like a profit-based royalty license, the price of the downstream product is not distorted by upstream costs.

  • Hybrid Licenses: Royalty plus Fixed Fee

some keywords:

patent thickets

royalty stacking

double marginalization

引文

the introduction of a new product or service often requires many complementary technologies

Abstract

Many key industries (e.g., biomedical, pharmaceuticals, telecommunications, and information technologies) are characterized by cumulative innovations, where the introduction of a new product or service often requires many complementary technologies. When these technologies are protected by intellectual property rights owned by many firms, patent thickets exist, which researchers have argued may hinder the development of cumulative innovations. Specifically, patent thickets may lead to excessive royalty burdens for potential licensees, which is called “royalty stacking,” and if such costs are passed on to consumers, prices of products based on cumulative technologies will be driven up, dubbed as “double marginalization.” The literature, however, does not address these issues under different forms of licensing contracts.

This article develops a game-theoretic model where a downstream firm seeks to license N patents that read on its product from upstream firms. It discusses a variety of licensing forms widely used in practice and attempts to discover whether royalty stacking and double marginalization occur under these forms of licenses. It also studies the impact of bargaining power between parties. It is found that when patent ownership becomes more fragmented, neither royalty stacking nor double marginalization occurs under profit-based royalty, fixed fee, and hybrid licenses. Such problems occur only under pure quantity-based or pure revenue-based royalty licenses when the downstream firm’s bargaining power is low. It is also shown that no matter how fragmented the ownership structure of patent is, hybrid licenses consisting of a fixed fee and a quantity- or revenue-based royalty rate lead to the same market outcomes as a fully integrated firm that owns all the patents and the downstream market.

This article has interesting implications for both research and practice. First, the results show that even under the same patent ownership structure, different forms of licenses lead to quite different market outcomes. Therefore, it is suggested that firms and policy makers pay more attention to contractual forms of licenses when trying to minimize the negative impact of patent thickets. Second, the extant literature has largely assumed that quantity-based royalties are used, where double marginalization is the most severe. In practice, revenue-based royalties are most common, under which double marginalization is much milder. Third, the results show that patent pools can be most effective in mitigating royalty stacking and double marginalization when quantity-based or revenue-based royalties are the sole or primary payment form, especially when downstream firms have low bargaining power.

References

  • Associated Press Financial Wire. 2007. Qualcomm announces record third quarter fiscal 2007 results. July 25.
  • Battersby, G. J., and C. W. Grimes. 2005. Licensing royalty rates. New York: Aspen Publishers.
  • Bessen, J., and R. Hunt. 2003. An empirical look at software patents. Working paper. Available at: http://www.researchoninnovation.org/swpat.pdf.
  • Bessen, J., and E. Maskin. 2009. Sequential innovation, patents, and imitation. Rand Journal of Economics 40 (4): 611–35.
  • Brunsvold, B. G., and D. P. O’Reilley. 2004. Drafting patent license agreements. Washington, DC: The Bureau of National Affairs.
  • Burns, S. 2007. Apple payment makes up 90 per cent of creative profit. ITnews, February 1. Available at: http://www.itnews.com.au/News/45179,apple-payment-makes-up-90-percent-of-creative-profit.aspx.
  • Cournot, A. 1838. Researches into the mathematical principles of the theory of wealth. Trans. N. Bacon. London: Macmillan.
  • Economides, N. 1996. The economics of networks. International Journal of Industrial Organization 16 (4): 673–99.
  • Foley Hoag LLP. 2007. Terms and trends in patent license agreements with universities and other research institutions. Available at: http://www.foleyhoag.com/NewsCenter/PressCenter/2007/05/Terms-and-Trends-050807.aspx.
  • Gans, J. S., D. H. Hsu, and S. Stern. 2002. When does start-up innovation spur the gale of creative destruction? Rand Journal of Economics 33 (4): 571–86.
  • Goldscheider, R. 1995. The negotiation of royalties and other sources of income from licensing. IDEA: The Journal of Law and Technology 36: 1–17.
  • Goldscheider, R., J. Jarosz, and C. Mulhem. 2005. Use of the 25% rule in valuing intellectual property. In Intellectual property: Valuation, exploitation, and infringement damages, ed. R. L.Parr, and G. V.Smith, 410–26. Hoboken, NJ: Wiley.
  • Goodman, D. J., and R. A. Myers. 2005. 3G cellular standards and patents. Proceedings of IEEE International Conference on Wireless Networks, Communications, and Mobile Computing. June 13.
  • Grindley, P. C., and D. J. Teece. 1997. Managing intellectual capital: Licensing and cross-licensing in semiconductors and electronics. California Management Review 39: 8–41.
  • Hall, B., and M. MacGarvie. 2006. The private value of software patents. NBER Working Paper No. 12195.
  • Heller, M. A., and R. S. Eisenberg. 1998. Can patents deter innovation? The anticommons in biomedical research. Science 280: 698–701.
  • Kamien, M. I. 1992. Patent licensing. In Handbook of game theory, vol. 1, ed. R. J.Aumann, and S.Hart, 332–54. Amsterdam: North-Holland.
  • Kamien, M. I., and Y. Tauman. 2002. Patent licensing: The inside story. Manchester School 70 (1): 7–15.
  • Kulatilaka, N., and L. Lin. 2006. Impact of licensing on investment and financing of technology development. Management Science 52 (12): 1824–37.
  • Lemley, M. A., and C. Shapiro. 2007. Patent holdup and royalty stacking. Texas Law Review 85: 1991–2049.
  • Lessig, L. 2001. The future of ideas: The fate of the commons in a connected world. New York: Random House.
  • Levine, A. 2009. Licensing and scale economies in the biotechnology pharmaceutical industry. Working paper, Stanford University.
  • Noguchi, Y. 2006. IPod patent dispute settled. Washington Post, August 24, p. D01. Available at: http://www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/content/article/2006/08/23/AR2006082301702.html.
  • Port, K. L., J. Dratler, F. M. Hammersley, T. P. McElwee, C. R. McManis, and B. A. Wrigley. 2005. Licensing intellectual property in the information age (2nd ed.). Durham, NC: Carolina Academic Press.
  • Preston, R. 2005. Profit pending. Network Computing, December 8.
  • Qualcomm Inc. 2008. Qualcomm business model: A formula for innovation & choice. White paper. Available at: http://www.qualcomm.com/documents/files/qualcomm-business-model-formula-innovation-choice.pdf.
  • Ricadela, A. 2006. Microsoft IP: A $900 million patent deficit. InformationWeek, April 3.
  • Seget, S. 2005. Biotechnology licensing: How has the balance of power shifted? Spectrum: Pharmaceutical Industry Dynamics, Decision Resources, Inc. October 21.
  • Shapiro, C. 2001. Navigating the patent thicket: Cross-licenses, patent pools, and standard-setting. In Innovation policy and the economy, Vol. 1, ed. A.Jaffe, J.Lerner, and S.Stern. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.
  • Slind-Flor, V. 2004. Goldscheider’s rule. IP Law & Business, August.
  • Stone, B. 2004. Nickels, dimes, billions: Big tech companies are raking in big bucks—a little at a time—by charging fees for use of their innovations. Newsweek (web exclusive), August 2. Available at: http://www.newsweek.com/2004/08/01/nickels-dimes-billions.html.
  • Via Licensing Corp. 2008. Via Licensing announces patent licensing terms for MPEG Surround. Press release. San Francisco, September 12. Available at: http://www.vialicensing.com/user-license-docs/newsreleasespdf/09_12_2008%20Via%20Licensing%20Announces%20Patent%20Licensing%20Terms%20for%20MPEG%20Surround.pdf.

Accepting Zero in the Ultimatum Game: Selfish Nash Response?

Date: 2013-01-01
By: Gianandrea Staffiero (Universitat Pompeu Fabra, Department of Economics and Business)
Filippos Exadaktylos (BELIS, Murat Sertel Center for Advanced Economic Studies, Istanbul Bilgi University)
Antonio M. Espín (Department of Economic Theory and Economic History, University of Granada.)
URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:gra:wpaper:13/01&r=net
The rejection of unfair proposals in ultimatum games is often quoted as evidence of other-regarding preferences. In this paper we focus on those responders who accept any proposals, setting the minimum acceptable offer (MAO) at zero. While this behavior could result from the randomization between the two payoff-maximizing strategies (i.e. setting MAO at zero or at the smallest positive amount), it also implies that the opponent’s payoff is maximized and the “pie” remains intact. We match subjects’ behavior as ultimatum responders with their choices in the dictator game, in two large-scale experiments. We find that those who set MAO at zero are the most generous dictators. Moreover, they differ substantially from responders whose MAO is the smallest positive offer, who are the greediest dictators. Thus, an interpretation of zero MAOs in terms of selfish, payoff-maximizing behavior could be misleading. Our evidence indicates that the restraint from punishing others can be driven by altruism and by the desire to maximize social welfare.
Keywords: ultimatum game, dictator game, altruism, social welfare, costly punishment, selfishness, social preferences.